1. INTRODUCTION
A starting point for a mathematical definition of risk is simply as standard deviation. The more risk we take, the more we stand to lose or gain. Standard deviation (or volatility) is a kind of simple risk measure. Different families of risk measures have been proposed in literature like coherent, convex, spectral risk measures, conditional value-at-risk etc. and discussed to measure or quantify the market risks in theoretical and practical perspectives. Risk measures are also linked to insurance premiums.
Markowitz [18] used the standard deviation to measure the market risk in his portfolio theory but his method doesn’t tell the difference between the positive and the negative deviation. Artzer et al. [1, 2] proposed a coherent risk measure in an axiomatic approach, and formulated the representation theorems. Fritelli [11] proposed sublinear risk measure to weaken coherent axioms. Heath [14] firstly studied the convex risk measures and Föllmer & Schied [8, 9, 10] and Frittelli & Rosazza Gianin [12] extended them to general probability spaces. They had weakened the conditions of positive homogeneity and subadditivity by replacing them with convexity.
There exist stochastic phenomena like Allais paradox and Ellsberg paradox which can not be dealt with linear mathematical expectation in economics. So Choquet [4] introduced a nonlinear expectation called Choquet expectation which applied to many areas such as statistics, economics and finance. Choquet expectation is equivalent to the convex(or coherent) risk measure if given capacity is submodular. But Choquet expectation has a difficulty in defining a conditional expectation. Peng [21] introduced a nonlinear expectation, g-expectation which is a solution of a nonlinear backward stochastic differential equation. It’s easy to define conditional expectation with Peng’s g-expectation (see papers[5, 13, 15, 17, 20, 22] for related topics).
In this paper, we show that the set of priors in the representation of Choquet expectation is the one of equivalent martingale measures under some conditions, when the distortion is submodular. That is, if a capacity c is submodular, then we have the representation
where Qc := {Q ∈ M1,f : Q[A] ≤ c(A) ∀A ∈ FT }. There is no specific explanation in the literature for the structure of the set Qc. It is worthy of examining it. By using g-expectation and related topics, we’ll show that
for some density generator set Θg.
This paper consists of as follows. Introduction is given in section 1. Definitions of Choquet expectation( or integral) and risk measures are stated in section 2. Definition of Peng’s g-expectation and related topics are given in section 3. The set of priors in the representation of Choquet expectation is discussed and the main Theorem 4.4 is given in section 4.
2. DEFINITIONS OF CHOQUET EXPECTATION( OR INTEGRAL) AND RISK MEASURES
In this section, we give definitions of Choquet expectation( or integral) and coherent( or convex) risk measures. Let (Ω,(Ft)t∈[0,T], P) be the given filtered probability space.
Definition 2.1. A set function c : F → [0, 1] is called monotone if
and normalized if
The monotone and normalized set function is called a capacity. A monotone set function is called submodular or 2-alternating if
Two real functions X and Y defined on Ω are called comonotonic if
A class of function X is said to be comonotonic if for every pair (X, Y ) ∈ X × X , X and Y are comonotonic.
Definition 2.2. Let ψ : [0, 1] → [0, 1] be increasing function with ψ(0) = 0 and ψ(1) = 1. The set function
is called distortion of P with respect to the distortion function ψ.
The cψ defined in Definition 2.2 becomes normalized monotone function. The notion of integral with respect to a capacity is due to Choquet [4].
Definition 2.3. Let c : F → [0, 1] be monotone and normalized set function. The Choquet integral or concave distortion risk measure of X ∈ L2(FT ) with respect to c is defined as
The following is the definition of coherent risk measure of which concept is borrowed from one of norm.
Definition 2.4. A coherent risk measure ρ : X → ℝ is a mapping satisfying for X, Y ∈ X
(1) ρ(X) ≥ ρ(Y ) if X ≤ Y (monotonicity),
(2) ρ(X + m) = ρ(X) − m for m ∈ ℝ (translation invariance),
(3) ρ(X + Y ) ≤ ρ(X) + ρ(Y ) (subadditivity),
(4) ρ(λX) = λρ(X) for λ ≥ 0 (positive homogeneity).
The subadditivity and the positive homogeneity can be relaxed to a weaker quantity, i.e. convexity
which means diversification should not increase the risk.
A convex risk measure ρ :→ ℝ is a functional satisfying monotonicity, translation invariance and convexity.
Definition 2.5. Choquet integral of the loss is defined as
where c is a capacity.
Choquet integral of the loss ρ : X → ℝ satisfies monotonicity, cash invariance, positive homogeneity and the others.
(1) ∫ λdc = λ for constant λ (constant preserving).
(2) If X ≤ Y , then ∫(−X)dc ≥ ∫(−Y )dc (monotonicity).
(3) For λ ≥ 0, ∫ λ(−X)dc = λ ∫(−X)dc (positive homogeneity).
(4) If X and Y are comonotone functions, then
.
(5) If c is submodular or concave function, then
3. PENG’S G-EXPECTATION
In this section, the definition of g-expectation is given. Let g : Ω×[0, T]×ℝ×ℝn → ℝ be a function that g ↦ g(t, y, z) is measurable for each (y, z) ∈ ℝ×ℝn and satisfy the following conditions
Theorem 3.1 ([21]). For every terminal condition ξ ∈ L2(FT ) := L2(Ω, FT , P) the following backward stochastic differential equation
has a unique solution
Definition 3.2. For each ξ ∈ L2(FT ) and for each t ∈ [0, T] g−expectation of X and the conditional g−expectation of X under Ft is respectively defined by
where yt is the solution of the BSDE (3.2).
3.1. Two sets of probability measures, and Let g be independent of y and g(t, y, 0) = 0. We define two sets of probability measures on the measurable space (Ω, FT ),
where t ∈ [0, T] and Θg is defined as
Let’s see properties of set of priors, Qc as in (1.1). Set
Then is a P-martingale since . Also is a P-density on FT since . A probability measure Qθ on (Ω, F) is equivalent to P, where Qθ is defined as
We can easily see that Qc is convex and weakly compact in L1(Ω, F, P). For every deterministic τ ∈ [0, T] and every B ∈ Fτ ,
where denotes the restriction of Q3 to Fτ (See the paper [23] for details).
If θ ∈ Θg, i.e. θt · z ≤ g(t, z), then we have θt · z ≤ |g(t, z)| ≤ K|z| and so |θt| ≤ K by taking z = θt. The Girsanov transformation implies that there exists a probability measure Qθ on the space (Ω, Ft) such that
and
, t ∈ [0, T] is a Qθ-Brownian motion.
The two prior sets, and are the same set under some conditions.
Theorem 3.3 ([16]). Let g be independent of y and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c). Then
Definition 3.4. Let g be independent of y and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c). The generator g is said to be sublinear with respect to z if for a ≥ 0, z1, z2 ∈ ℝd
Theorem 3.5 ([16]). Let g be independent of y and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c). Then
∀ξ ∈ L2(Ω, Ft, P) if and only if g is sublinear with respect to z.
4. THE SET OF PRIORS IN THE REPRESENTATION OF CHOQUET EXPECTATION
The following theorem is about the equivalent properties on the Choquet integral with respect to a capacity c.
Theorem 4.1 ([7]). For the Choquet integral with respect to a capacity c, the followings are equivalent.
(1) ρ(X) := ∫(−X) dc is a convex risk measure on L2(FT ).
(2) ρ(X) := ∫(−X) dc is a coherent risk measure on L2(FT ).
(3) For Qc := {Q ∈ M1,f : Q[A] ≤ c(A) ∀A ∈ FT },
where M1,f := M1,f (Ω, F) is the set of all finitely additive normalized set functions Q : F → [0, 1].
(4) The set function c is submodular. In this case, Qc = Qmax, where Qmax := {Q ≪ P : αmin(Q) = 0} is in the representation of the convex risk measure
Peng’s g-expectation provides various features. We will use the properties of g-expectation to investigate the set of prior, Qc. The classical mathematical expectation can be represented by the Choquet expectation if g is linear function of z. The following theorem deals with the one-dimensional Brownian motion case, and y, z ∈ ℝ.
Theorem 4.2 ([3]). Suppose that g satisfies the conditions (3.1a), (3.1b) and (3.1c). Then there exists a Choquet expectation whose restriction to L2(Ω, F, P) is equal to a g-expectation if and only if g is independent of y and is linear in z, i.e. there exists a continuous function νt such that
Set g(y, z, t) = νtz through the last of this paper. Then Choquet expectation is equal to g-expectation by Theorem 4.2. I.e., there exist a capacity cg such that
If we take ξ = IA for A ∈ F in (4.2), then the capacity cg satisfies
Then we can prove that cg is submodular.
Theorem 4.3. The capacity cg in (4.2) is submodular.
Proof. By Dellacherie’s theorem in Dellacherie [6], Choquet expectation on L2(Ω, F, P) is comonotonic additive. That is, if Ɛg is Choquet expectation, then we have Ɛg[ξ + η] = Ɛg[ξ] + Ɛg[η] whenever ξ and η are comonotonic.
Note that IA∪B and IA∩B is a pair of comonotone functions for all A, B ∈ F. Hence comonotonicity and subadditivity of Ɛg imply
So the proof is done. ☐
Since cg is submodular, by Theorem 4.1 we have the representation
where Qcg := {Q ∈ M1,f : Q[A] ≤ cg(A) ∀A ∈ FT }.
The following is the main theorem.
Theorem 4.4. where Qcg is the prior set in the representation (4.3).
Notice that is defined as
where t ∈ [0, T] and Θg is defined as
Proof. Since has the same expression as
becomes Qcg. Since g(y, z, t) = νtz is independent of y and satisfy the conditions (3.1a) and (3.1c), = by Theorem 3.3. Therefore, we have . ☐
In fact, for the linear function g(t, y, z) = νtz, let us consider the BSDE
The above differential equation (4.4) is reduced to
By Girsanov’s Theorem, -Brownian motion under Qν defined as
Therefore we have the relations
which means g-expectation is a classical mathematical expectation.
References
- P. Artzner, F. Delbaen, J.-M. Eber & D. Heath: Thinking coherently. Risk 10 (1997), 68-71.
- ______: Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance 9 (1999), 203-223. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9965.00068
- Z. Chen, T. Chen & M. Davison: Choquet expectation and Peng’s g-expectation. The Annals of Probability 33 (2005), 1179-1199. https://doi.org/10.1214/009117904000001053
- G. Choquet: Theory of capacities. Ann. Inst. Fourier (Grenoble) 5 (1953), 131-195.
- F. Coquet, Y. Hu, J. Mémin & S. Peng: Filtration consistent nonlinear expectations and related g-expectations. Probability Theory and Related Fields 123 (2002), 1-27. https://doi.org/10.1007/s004400100172
- C. Dellacherie: Quelques commentaires sur les prolongements de capacités. Séminaire de Probabilités V. Strasbourg. Lecture Notes in Math. 191 Springer, 77-81, 1970.
- H. Föllmer & A. Schied: Stochastic Finance: An Introduction in Discrete Time. Springer-Verlag, New York, 2002.
- ______: Convex measures of risk and trading constraints. Finance & Stochastics 6 (2002), 429-447. https://doi.org/10.1007/s007800200072
- ______: Robust preferences and convex measures of risk, in: Advances in Finance and Stochastics, K. Sandmann and P.J. Schönbucher eds., Springer-Verlag.
- ______: Stochastic Finance: An introduction in discrete time. Walter de Gruyter, Berlin, 2004.
- M. Frittelli: Representing sublinear risk measures and pricing rules. http://www.mat.unimi.it/users/frittelli/pdf/Sublinear2000.pdf, 2000.
- M. Frittelli & E. Rosazza Gianin: Putting order in risk measures. Journal of Banking & Finance 26 (2002), 1473-1486. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0378-4266(02)00270-4
- K. He, M. Hu & Z. Chen: The relationship between risk measures and Choquet expectations in the framework of g-expectations. Statistics and Probability Letters 79 (2009), 508-512. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spl.2008.09.025
- D. Heath: Back to the future. Plenary lecture at the First World Congress of the Bachelier Society, Paris, June 2000.
- L. Jiang: Convexity, translation invariance and subadditivity for g-expectation and related risk measures. Annals of Applied Provability 18 (2006), 245-258.
- ______: A necessary and sufficient condition for probability measures dominated by g-expectation. Statistics and Probability Letters 79 (2009), 196-201. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spl.2008.07.037
- N. El Karoui, S.G. Peng & M.-C. Quenez: Backward stochastic differential equations in finance. Math. Finance 7 (1997), 1-71. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9965.00022
- H. Markowitz: Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance 26 (1952), 1443-1471.
- S. Peng: Backward SDE and related g-expectation, backward stochastic DEs. Pitman 364 (1997), 141-159.
- E. Pardoux & S.G. Peng: Adapted solution of a backward stochastic differential equation. Systems and Control Letters 14 (1990), 55-61. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-6911(90)90082-6
- S. Peng: Backward SDE and related g-expectations, in: Backward stochastic differential equations, N. El Karoui and L. Mazliak eds., Pitman Res. Notes Math. Ser., 364 (1997), 141-159.
- E. Rosazza Gianin: Some examples of risk measures via g-expectations. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 39 (2006), 19-34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.insmatheco.2006.01.002
- Zengjing Chen & Larry Epstein: Ambiguity, risk and asset returns in continuous time. Econometrica 70 (2002), 1403-1443. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00337